Accounting Numbers and Economic Values

DOI10.1177/0003603X8202700106
Published date01 March 1982
Date01 March 1982
AuthorGeorge J. Benston
Subject MatterArticle
The Antitrust Bulletin/Spring
1982
Accounting numbers and
economic values
BY GEORGE J. BENSTON*
161
The accounting data produced by companies, either for internal
managerial purposes or for published financial statements, have
often been presented in legal cases involving antitrust issues or
other economic questions. Unfortunately, many lawyers and
economists seem unaware of the inherent limitations of numbers
produced by a company's accounting system. These limitations
are so severe that, in general, these data do not provide valid
measurements that can be used for answering or gaining insights
into most economic questions.
In the paragraphs that follow, I give my reasons for this
conclusion and provide illustrative examples. I can summarize the
reasoning, as follows. The economic concepts
of
assets, liabili-
ties, income and expense necessarily are subjectively determined.
Accounting, however, is concerned primarily with recording data
to meet the requirements and peculiarities
of
specific business
organization and managers. Their familiarity with the business
Professor of Accounting, Economics and Finance in the Graduate
School of Management, University of Rochester.
AUTHOR'S NOTE:
An
earlier version
of
this paper was prepared as an
affidavit before the Federal Trade Commission in the matter
of
the
Omnibus Automobile Industry Investigation, File No.
761-0083
(Octo-
ber 1979), at the request
of
GeneralMotors Corporation.
©1982by Federal Legal Publications, Inc.
162
:The antitrust bulletin
and the accounting system allows them to use the numbers
effectively. But, for others who are not in this position, the
internal accounting numbers generated by an enterprise's ac-
counting system often provide measures that can be very inac-
curate and misleading.
Section A presents a more complete analysis of the reasons
for the profound difference between accounting measurements
and economic concepts. Next, section B provides some important
examples of these differences. Section C gives examples
of
ac-
counting inconsistencies among different companies (such as
inventory and depreciation accounting). Section D illustrates and
discusses examples of inconsistencies among and within compa-
nies of methods used to assign and allocate costs to specific
products or enterprise segments. These include the pricing
of
intracompany transfers and the allocation
of
joint and common
company costs. Section E briefly delineates examples
of
some
important inconsistencies between U.S. and foreign accounting
practices. Section F presents some estimates
of
the magnitude and
significance of the differences between accounting measurements
and economic concepts. Finally, section G discusses why, in
consideration of the overwhelming prevalence and magnitude
of
these differences, companies incur the expense of keeping ac-
counting records. As is pointed out above, the reason is that the
accounting data are useful for internal control, but are not
designed or often useful for the measurements demanded by
economists and lawyers.
A. Economic
compared
to accounting definitions
The economic determination
of
asset values and income
The value of an asset is determined by its usefulness to its
owner in comparison with alternative means
of
providing the
owner with desired services (called "utility" by economists). Since
the utility of any asset depends on the particular desires
of
individuals, a common unit
of
measure is required. Economists
Accounting numbers :163
measure utility in terms
of
cash because, being the medium
of
exchange, it can be exchanged at a very low transactions cost for
other goods and services. Thus, the value
of
an asset is measured
in terms of the net cash flow (the monetary value
of
utility) it is
expected to yield its owner as long as the owner expects to keep it.
The word "net" in the phrase "net cash flow" refers to the
cash that the asset yields, less the cash outflows required to bring
about the inflows. The cash flow may be derived from several
sources. For example, the coupons on a bond provide its owner
with a periodic (e.g., semiannual) cash flow offset only by the
expense
of
mailing the coupons and receiving the interest check.
A machine produces a product that yields a cash flow when the
product is sold. But this inflow is reduced by the outflow
of
cash
expended for the power and labor needed to run the machine and
the materials used to produce the product. Or, the cash flow
derived from an asset may be measured by the net savings it
allows the owner to achieve, as when an owned building permits
the owner to save rent (but necessitates cash outflows for taxes
and other expenditures that the landlord would have made).
Finally, an asset may yield its owner utility in the form
of
nonpecuniary benefits, such as the aesthetic pleasure or pride of
owning a famous painting. In these instances, the net cash flow
may be approximated by the amount
of
cash the owner gives up
by not selling the painting. These and similar net cash flows are
derived from the "use value"
of
an asset. Another value is its
"exchange value," the net cash amount that could be obtained
were the asset sold. In general, the net cash flow used to measure
the value
of
an asset is the next best alternative use
of
the asset to
the owner, including sale
of
the asset if its value in exchange is
greater than its value in use. Therefore, the value in use
of
an
asset is generally higher than its value in exchange, because
otherwise it would be sold.
Determining the rfet cash flows that are expected to be derived
from an asset (from use or exchange) is necessary
but
not
sufficient for determining its economic value. The timing
of
the
net cash flows also is a required datum, since cash that can be

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT