Estimating dynamic R&D choice: an analysis of costs and long‐run benefits

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/1756-2171.12181
AuthorMark J. Roberts,Bettina Peters,Helmut Fryges,Van Anh Vuong
Published date01 May 2017
Date01 May 2017
RAND Journal of Economics
Vol.48, No. 2, Summer 2017
pp. 409–437
Estimating dynamic R&D choice: an analysis
of costs and long-run benefits
Bettina Peters
Mark J. Roberts∗∗
Van Anh Vuong∗∗∗
and
Helmut Fryges∗∗∗∗
This article estimates a dynamic structural model of discrete Research and Development (R&D)
investment and quantifies its cost and long-run benefit for German manufacturing firms. The
model incorporates linkages between R&D choice, product and process innovations, and future
productivity and profits. The long-run payoff to R&D is the proportional difference in expected
firm value generated by the investment. It increases firm value by 6.7% for the median firm in
high-tech industries but only 2.8% in low-tech industries. Simulations show that reductions in
maintenance costs of innovation significantly raise investment rates and productivity, whereas
reductions in startup costs have little effect.
1. Introduction
Firm investment in R&D is a key mechanism generating improvements in firm perfor mance
over time. Estimating the ex post return to the firm’s R&D investment has been a major focus of
empirical studies for decades, with most of the empirical literature built around the knowledge
Centre for European Economic Research (ZEW); b.peters@zew.de.
∗∗Pennsylvania State University and NBER; mroberts@psu.edu.
∗∗∗University of Cologne; vananh.vuong@ewi.uni-koeln.de.
∗∗∗∗University of Tasmania; helmut.fryges@utas.edu.au.
We are grateful to Uli Doraszelski, Jordi Jaumandreu, Ken Judd, Florin Maican, Jacques Mairesse, Matilda Orth,
Joris Pinkse, Marc Rysman, Spiro Stefanou, Jim Tybout, Daniel Xu, Hongsong Zhang, and three referees for helpful
comments and discussions. Wethank particpants at the ZEW Conference on Innovation and Patenting (Mannheim, 2013),
IIOC (Boston, 2013), EEA (Gothenburg, 2013), German Economic Association (D¨
usseldorf, 2013), EARIE (Evora,
2013), CDM Workshop (London, 2013), Conference on Innovation and Entrepreneurship (Copenhagen, 2014), MaCCI
Annual Conference (Mannheim, 2014), Berlin IO Day (2016), as well as seminars at universities of Cologne (2013),
Brussels (2013), Valencia (2013), Turin (2013), Barcelona (2013), Cornell (2013), Leuven (2013), Tinbergen Institutue
Amersterdam (2013), Heidelberg (2014), W¨
urzburg (2014), Gothenberg (2014), Duke (2014), Oregon (2014), ETH
(2016), Zurich (2016), Copenhagen Business School (2016). We thank the Centre for European Economic Research
(ZEW) for providing data access and research support.
C2017, The RAND Corporation. 409
410 / THE RAND JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
production function developed by Griliches (1979). In this framework, firm investment in R&D
creates a stock of knowledge that enters into the firm’s production function as an additional input
along with physical capital, labor, and materials. The marginal product of this knowledge input
provides a measure of the return to the firm’s investment in R&D and has been the primary focus
of the empirical innovation literature.
The goal of this article is to estimate the expected payoff to R&D investment at the firm
level. Unlike most of the empirical literature that relies on the knowledge production function,
we focus on the firm’s R&D investment decision. The discrete decision to invest in R&D contains
information on the costs of innovation and the expected long-run payoffto the firm from engaging
in R&D investment. We develop a dynamic structural model of the firm’s choice to invest in
R&D, estimate the model using microdata on German manufacturing firms, and summarize the
implicit expected long-run payoff to R&D that rationalizes the firm’s observed R&D investment
decision.
Our model of the firm’s dynamic R&D choice captures five important features of the R&D
investment process. The first is the impact of R&D on the probability that the firm realizes
a product or process innovation. The second is the effect of these realized innovations on the
firm’s revenue productivity and short-run profitability. Third, these effects can be long lived,
affecting the incentives of the firm to invest in the future and impacting the long-run value of
the firm. Fourth, there is uncertainty surrounding the effect of R&D on innovation and the effect
of innovation on productivity. Fifth, the cost of generating innovations is likely to differ between
firms based on their size and whether they are spending to maintain ongoing R&D activities
or establishing new R&D programs. Incorporating these features into the model, the structural
parameters characterize the linkages between R&D, innovation, and productivity as well as the
costs of producing innovations.
Weuse the model to estimate the long-r un payoff to R&D for a sample of German manufac-
turing firms across a range of high-tech and low-tech industries. The data source is the Mannheim
Innovation Panel (MIP) collected by the Centre for European Economic Research (ZEW). This
is the German contribution to the Community Innovation Survey (CIS) that is collected for most
countries within the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). The
key features of the MIP survey that we utilize are questions on product and process innovations
realized by the firm, R&D input measures, production expenditure, capital stocks, and firm sales.
The structural estimates can be briefly summarized. First, firms that invest in R&D have a
substantially higher probability of realizing product or process innovations; but R&D investment
is neither necessary nor sufficient for firm innovation. The group of high-tech manufactur-
ing industries has a higher probability of innovation, given R&D, than the group of low-tech
industries. Second, product as well as process innovations lead to increases in future firm pro-
ductivity; but product innovations are more important for the high-tech industries, whereas
process innovations are more important for the low-tech industries. Third, firm productivity is
highly persistent over time, which implies that innovations that raise productivity have long-
run effects on firm performance. Fourth, the cost of generating innovations is significantly
smaller for firms that are maintaining ongoing R&D investment rather than beginning to in-
vest in R&D. This means that firm R&D history is an important determinant of current R&D
behavior.
Using the structural parameters, we estimate the expected payoff to firm R&D as the pro-
portional difference in the expected future value of a firm when it invests in R&D versus when
it does not. This expected payoff varies with the productivity, capital stock, age, and industry of
the firm and can be constructed for all firms, not just firms that choose to invest. We find that the
expected payoff varies substantially across industries and across firms within each industr y. For
the five high-tech industries, a firm with the median productivity, capital stock, and age has an
expected payoff equal to 6.7% of firm value. In the seven low-tech industries, the corresponding
payoffis 2.8%. Our results show that the difference between the high-tech and low-tech industries
arises from differences in the magnitude of the effect of innovation on the firm’s productivity
C
The RAND Corporation 2017.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT