S&P 500 Membership and Managers’ Supply of Conservative Financial Reports

Published date01 May 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jbfa.12200
Date01 May 2016
Journal of Business Finance & Accounting
Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 43(5) & (6), 543–571, May/June 2016, 0306-686X
doi: 10.1111/jbfa.12200
S&P 500 Membership and Managers’
Supply of Conservative Financial Reports
GREGORY W. MARTIN,WAYNE B. THOMAS AND MATTHEW M. WIELAND
Abstract: Our study is motivated by economic theory and the debate among practitioners,
standard setters, and academics on the role of conditional conservatism in financial reporting.
We find that managers provide less conditionally conservative financial reports after their
firms are added to the Standard and Poor’s (S&P) 500 index. S&P 500 membership is
expected to reduce information asymmetry between managers and outside stakeholders due
to an increased flow of public and private information. As a result, the contracting benefits
of conservative accounting choices are reduced, and managers are less willing to provide
conditionally conservative reports. In contrast, we find that managers provide more conditionally
conservative financial reports after their firms are deleted from the index. Firms being deleted
from the S&P 500 index probably incur an increase in information asymmetry. Overall, our
results provide evidence consistent with conditional conservatism being a response by managers
to the information needs of financial statements users.
Keywords: conservatism, S&P 500, information asymmetry, earnings quality, agency theory
1. INTRODUCTION
In this study we examine the change in firms’ conservatism around addition to
or deletion from the Standard and Poor’s (S&P) 500 index. Changes in S&P 500
membership are expected to have a significant effect on the firm’s information
asymmetry and therefore affect the contracting benefits of conservative accounting.
Our study is motivated by the current debate over the role of conservatism (prudence)
in financial reporting (Andr´
e et al., 2015; Mora and Walker, 2015; Ruch and Taylor,
2015).
The FASB’s conceptual framework (SFAC 8) rejects unconditional conservatism
based on the notion that it compromises neutrality, even though conditional
The first author is from the University of North Carolina-Charlotte; the second author is from the University
of Oklahoma; the third author is from Miami University.The authors thank Brad Badertscher, Brian Burnett,
Daniel Beneish, Joe Fisher, John Hassell, Nathan Stuart, Jim Wahlen, and workshop participants at Indiana
University,University of Notre Dame, and Purdue University for their helpful comments on this manuscript.
The authors wish to thank an anonymous referee and Martin Walker (Editor) for helpful comments and
suggestions on earlier versions of this paper. (Paper received July 2015, revised revision accepted February
2016).
Address for correspondence: Gregory W. Martin University of North Carolina-Charlotte, 9201 University
City Blvd. Charlotte, NC 28223.
e-mail: gmarti44@uncc.edu
C
2016 John Wiley & Sons Ltd 543
544 MARTIN, THOMAS AND WIELAND
conservatism is mandated in many recent standards (e.g., SFAS 121, 142, 144).1While
the IASB’s conceptual framework retains the term prudence (IASB ED-2015-3), the
Basis for Conclusion notes the view by some that prudence could lead to greater
subjectivity and lack of neutrality in financial statements, making it difficult to assess
an entity’s financial performance.2Some academic research corroborates this view by
finding that conditional conservatism reduces the usefulness of accounting information
(Dichev and Tang, 2008; Gigler et al., 2009; Chen et al., 2014). There is also concern
that conservatism allows for the creation of hidden reserves or excessive provisions
in the current period which can be used to strategically manage earnings upward in
future periods (Paton, 1932, pp. 421–422; CAP, 1939; Levitt, 1998 (unconditional);
Jackson and Liu, 2010 (conditional)).
In contrast, the IASB also discusses the views by others that prudence may increase
the usefulness of accounting information to the firm’s stakeholders. The Basis for
Conclusions suggests that prudence can reduce moral hazard by better aligning the
interests of managers and shareholders, is needed to counteract management’s natural
bias towards optimism, and is consistent with investors’ greater concern for downside
risk. These benefits suggest that the existence of conservatism can be explained by
its contracting role in the presence of information asymmetry (Watts, 2003).3These
views are also confirmed in prior research that documents an association between debt
contracting and conservative accounting (e.g., Wittenberg-Moerman, 2008; Zhang,
2008; Nikolaev, 2010; Tan, 2013; Khurana and Wang, 2015). Creditors are more
likely to use their bargaining power (through cost of debt) to demand timelier
recognition of losses because they face downside risk. Other stakeholders are also
likely to use their bargaining power to demand conservative accounting, such as strong
boards of directors (Beekes et al., 2004; Ahmed and Duellman, 2007), large investors
(Ramalingegowda and Yu, 2012; Cheng et al., 2015), big auditors (Krishnan, 2005;
2007; Cano-Rodriguez, 2010), and material customers and suppliers (Hui et al., 2012).
The literature argues that these parties demand conservatism, and managers respond
because the contracting benefits outweigh the costs of doing so.
We examine the link between conservative accounting and information asymmetry
using a sample of firms that are added to and deleted from the Standard and
Poor’s (S&P) 500 index. This setting for investigating whether managers’ supply of
conservatism is affected by information asymmetry is useful for several reasons. First,
managers and board members cannot select their own firm for membership, nor are
they likely to be able to predict such an event far in advance. Instead, our research
setting allows us to test the extent to which managers adjust their level of conservatism
in response to membership announcement. Our setting includes an exogenous shock
to a firm’s information environment, which allows us to infer a causal link between a
change in information asymmetry and conditional conservatism.
1 Beaver and Ryan (2005) adopt the term “conditional conservatism” to distinguish the asymmetric
timeliness of gain/loss recognition from “unconditional conservatism”, the predetermined understatement
of the book value of net assets. In this paper, we focus exclusively on conditional conservatism but for
expediency often refer to it simply as “conservatism”.
2 The Basis for Conclusion discusses both “cautious prudence” and “asymmetric prudence”, where the latter
relates more closely to the concept of conditional conservatism.
3 The existence of conservatism may also be explained by the firm avoiding litigation, income taxes, political
costs and reducing the cost of debt and equity capital (Basu, 1997; Watts, 2003; Qiang, 2007).
C
2016 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT